Book Review: The End of the Free Market: Who Wins the War Between
States and Corporations? – by Ian Bremmer (Portfolio/Penguin 2010)
This is an interesting book much about state capitalism –
capitalism assisted and otherwise propped up by states through nationalized
industries, sovereign wealth funds, and other mechanisms. The strong influence
of these state capitalisms on the global free market show that the concept of a
global free market is illusory or at best only partial. The Global Recession of
2008 precipitated by actions in free market countries was widely seen among
communistic champions and other state-empowered countries as a failure of the
free market and proof of its inherent weakness. The response to the global
crash was invariably state intervention by countries throughout the world
including and especially free market countries. Shortly thereafter Bremmer was
in a meeting led by a Chinese businessman to determine what should be the role
of the state in economies. He answered that they should stabilize the economies
and then fall back. He argued that the role of the state was simply to
stabilize through temporary stimulation. That is what happened in many
countries in multiple pulses then they backed off and let the economy catch
back up. It seems to have worked out fine although anti-capitalists may still
see it as proof of fundamental flaws in capitalism.
Bremmer first notes that the G7 nations are now less
relevant than the G20 which include free market skeptics like Russia, China,
Saudi Arabia, and to a lesser extent India. When the Soviet Union collapsed and
opened up to free markets one result was massive corruption where certain
people got wealthy at the expense of others. The transition from a command
economy to a free market proved difficult and chaotic and was only partially
made. Putin and his faction entered to restore order to the chaos and a return
to some level of authoritarianism and state control.
“Authoritarian governments everywhere have learned to
compete internationally by embracing market-driven capitalism.”
Of course, they do it with a huge caveat that preserves
state power. This is what has come to be known as state capitalism. He notes
that the apparent success of state capitalisms like Russia, China, and the Arab
Gulf state monarchies have attracted imitators in the developing world.
Communism is pretty much dead, he proclaims, although many
hybrid and authoritarian governments remain. His evidence? Post-2008 global
crash there was no resurgence of communism anywhere as one might expect from a
breakdown of free market functioning. All countries now embrace free market
capitalism to some degree. Even the so-called ‘socialist revolutions’ of
Venezuela and Ecuador have been partial, mainly through nationalization of
industries. Francis Fukuyama in his book The
End of History, predicted that consensus would bring all world governments
into the Western liberal democracy model but 2008 analysis declared only 18% of
countries as full democracies, 30% as flawed democracies, and 52% as either
hybrid democracies or authoritarian states. Another analysis rated 63% of
countries as electoral democracies but only 47% as “free countries.” The prediction
that globalization, of transportation, communications, and business, would
homogenize the world and effectively dilute hybrid, authoritarian states, and
dictatorships has not rung true. These states, manipulative of free markets and
often with poor free speech and human rights records have adapted and
persisted. Globalization has resulted in less decision-making power by
individual countries and more by organizations: International Monetary Fund,
International Criminal Court, UN, World Bank, or regional orgs like EU, etc.
The EU, though the most successful multinational organization, still retains
significant power for each nation-state. Nation-states remain the unified unit
that is most functional, providing order and assuring rights. They are the basis
for national pride and are the recognition sought by those ethnic groups who
fall under larger powers such as the Kurds.
Well-funded multinational corporations also wield
considerable power. These companies can site in different countries to lower
their tax burdens and increase profit margins. Some multinationals have
economies bigger than countries: a 2000 study concluded that 51 of the world’s
biggest economies were corporations. Since around 1990 a growing percentage of
multinational corporations, of investment, has come from developing countries,
many from Southeast Asia. These ‘emerging markets’ have been steadily gaining
investment market share. The privatization of previous very inefficient state
monopolies in Europe and among developed countries has made them more
profitable and their products cheaper for consumers, especially in combination
with freer trade policies. These policies led to more free flow of goods. These
liberal economic policies ruled the day from the 1990’s until the late 2000’s when
the power of state capitalisms waned due to the financial crisis. State-owned
companies have emerged as significant players in the global economy with some
among the world’s largest companies. Government bail-outs of large companies
considered “too big to fail” is also a form of state capitalism, but one of
temporary stimulus rather than being propped up and controlled by governments.
Thus, he argues, market power has been transferred from financial centers to
political centers. He notes that:
“State capitalism is not the reemergence of socialist
central planning in a twenty-first-century package. It is a form of
bureaucratically engineered capitalism particular to each government that
practices it.”
It is a recipe for a distorted global economy, he thinks. He
asks whether it will undermine economic growth and globalization, both of which
have lifted hundreds of millions out of poverty.
He offers a chapter of a brief history of capitalism. The
functional definition here is that capitalism is simply “the use of wealth to
create more wealth.” Private ownership and trading of land, labor, and capital
is inherent in most capitalist systems until the advent of state capitalisms.
Advocates of pure capitalism, or laissez-faire capitalism, want the state to
stay out of business and let Adam Smith’s “invisible hand” work its magic.
However, even in the U.S. the state is expected to be referee and some services
are expected to be provided by the state: national defense, criminal justice,
disaster relief, health insurance for the vulnerable, to name a few. This makes
even the countries most invested in free market advocation economies of “mixed”
capitalism. This is the dominant post-WWII economy.
Free markets lead to prosperity which leads to middles
classes which demand better government which implies better transparency and
accountability of government, which in turn makes free markets function better.
However, state capitalisms differ in that they see a much larger government
role and more government control. While the term “state capitalism” has meant
several different things through the years its definition is fairly clear these
days.
Continuing with the history he considers mercantilism which
he defines as: “economic nationalism for the purpose of building a wealthy and
powerful state.” The establishment of trade monopolies by early colonialists is
mercantilism and this led to conflicts. The British and Dutch East India
companies became powerful merchants/mercantilists, backed by governments and
monarchies. These were arguably the first “national champions,” or nationalized
companies. The mercantilists and their governments were arguably the first
state capitalists. Increased ease of oceanic transport and subsequent increased
ease of smuggling as well as more political influence by a wider number of
citizens and groups precipitated the downfall of mercantilism. Adam Smith
complained that a system that cheated consumers by limiting their choices could
not be relied upon. Mercantilism also manifested protectionism. Britain was the
first to drop it in favor of free markets. The U.S. did not follow fully until
the late 19th and early 20th centuries. Since then the
U.S. has been firmly on the laissez-faire end of capitalism. Of course, the
Great Depression of 1929 and the Great Recession of 2008 saw significant state
intervention in the U.S.
Few doubt that free trade fuels prosperity. “Mercantilism is
dead, but its influence continues.” Protectionism has become subtler. He mentions
agricultural subsidies and tariffs in Europe. In other cases, state capitalists
often choose consolidation of state power over full free trade, competition,
and unfortunately human rights.
The division between the free market and state capitalism is
not always clear. Government regulation of and participation in economic
activity varies among countries. Bremmer gives a graphic of the market spectrum
from utopian communism to command economies to state capitalism on one end to
free market capitalism to utopian libertarianism at the other end.
The 2008 recession originated in the U.S. as a result of
poor credit regulation, poor regulation of speculative leveraging of borrowed
capital, and nonregulation of the so-called shadow banking system – mainly hedge
funds and private equity firms. Thus the U.S. was very far to the right on the
spectrum of poorly regulated capitalism, he argues. The resulting bubble is
largely seen as a huge failure of government oversight. Before the 2008
recession many governments were steadily moving toward the right of the
spectrum but after the recession there has been considerable retreat back
toward the left of the spectrum, he argues. The early part of this was meant to
correct immediate problems.
The Scandinavian countries – Sweden, Norway, Finland,
Denmark, and Iceland, have managed to develop high living standards and small
gaps between rich and poor. They did it through social welfare, high taxes, and
income redistribution. They have some state-owned companies but most are
privatized. They have globally successful private companies. He mentions France
having much of its industry damaged in WWII, having moved left on the spectrum (apparently
partly due to a nationalistic desire to be opposite Anglo-Saxon trends), and
added state ownership of several industries.
State capitalism: 1) long-term policy to prioritize
political power 2) markets seen to serve national interests. It’s not
ideological. It’s not socialism. It can enable autocracy as in Arab monarchies
and some authoritarian energy-rich states.
There are three main tools of state capitalism: national oil
(and gas) companies (NOCs), other state-owned enterprises (SOEs), and sovereign
wealth funds (SWFs). NOCs began with one goal of hedging against rising oil
prices by acquiring supply. He notes that three quarters of oil reserves are
now owned by national oil companies (this may have dropped a bit since
publication). These companies are some of the largest energy companies. In
contrast the largest multinational companies (like Exxon, Shell, Chevron, and
BP) own just 10% of global production and 3% of reserves. They do, however,
have much greater technical knowledge and efficiency than the NOCs. They have
been basically selling this technology to the NOCs. Some of the NOCs are only
partially state-owned (like Norway’s Statoil which is 60+% state-owned). Some
have suffered from inefficiencies like Mexico’s Pemex which recently was
privatized. Saudi Aramco is also expected to be at least partially privatized
in the near future. Iran, Venezuela, Algeria, the Arab Gulf states, Brazil,
China, Russia, Malaysia, and others all have different NOC models. All are
managed and propped by the state in various ways. In some countries like
Venezuela they are by far the main source of the country’s revenue. Such
countries are very susceptible to oil price drops. China has three NOCs active
throughout the world competing for reserves and supply contracts. One advantage
of NOCs is that they don’t have shareholders and can negotiate better with
repressive regimes that have supply. Supply acquisition is primary and profit
is secondary. Russia’s gas monopoly Gazprom has leveraged supply and used
dependence geopolitically to threaten its neighbors, threatening to cut off
supply for Ukraine (which has had to find other sources of gas) and charge
different prices to end users often as a form of punishment for ex-Soviet bloc
countries. In any case, the motives for running NOCs are most often political.
Thus, this ‘resource nationalism’ which can include minerals and other
resources is a key tool for state capitalisms. Russia is king in resource
nationalism and has caused some grief with their multinational company
partners. The inefficiencies, lower wages, and lower experience of NOCs tends
to make oil prices rise although the recent gluts may indicate that this is
changing.
Every country has some state-owned enterprises. These SOEs
may include things like Amtrak, Center for Public Broadcasting, and the postal
service in the U.S. In state capitalisms like China there are many of these
SOEs, some quite large. There are electric utilities, banks, and auto companies
in China that are state-owned. Angola has a national diamond company,
Kazakhstan one for uranium, and Morocco one for phosphates. Brazil’s Lula da Silva
pressed private mining giant Vale, formerly state-owned, to return to favor a
political approach of providing jobs over profits. Such companies Bremmer calls
‘privately owned national champions.’ These companies share some political
goals with the state and balance that with their need for sufficient profit.
Governments may own large stakes too so they grade into SOEs. Governments can
use taxes as leverage and offer contracting and bid rigging to the companies,
essentially guaranteed contracts. He mentions the economic rise of post-WWII
Japan, a planned model of integrated companies or subsidiaries with state goals
in mind. The model was efficient as businesses complimented each other. South
Korea followed a similar path. These national champions also buy and invest in
projects in developed countries.
Sovereign wealth funds are “state-managed pools of excess
cash that can be invested strategically.” SWFs are also used by countries that
are not state capitalisms. There are three main sources of income for SWFs: resource
export income from state-owned companies, excess cash from a positive trade
balance including profits and taxes, and transfers from a federal budget or
foreign-exchange reserves. Like stock funds they are designed to maximize
returns. SWFs have been around since the 1950’s with Kuwait’s 1953 Investment
Authority created by British administrators. Brazil, India, Angola, Bolivia,
and Thailand are the latest to join this type of funding. There are now (2010)
50 SWFs with half created since 2000. These funds took a big hit during the
global recession. The funds can help countries survive commodity price drops
and they can hedge against inflation. They can also hedge against having to
seek help from entities like the IMF. Some are transparent like Norway’s fund
or those of Chile or South Korea and others more secretive as in the more
authoritarian states generally. Some U.S. states: Alaska, Wyoming, New Mexico,
and Alabama have similar type funds. China’s funds are the most secretive but
one could counter that U.S. hedge funds and private equity in the private
sector can also be also quite secretive. Authoritarian state capitalists,
however, have the largest SWFs, China with three of the eleven largest. Bremmer
thinks that the role of SWFs will grow in the future.
Emerging markets: China, Russia, India, Brazil, South Korea,
Mexico, Turkey, Thailand, Malaysia, and others have also spurred more state
involvement in national economies. The 1980s and 90s saw these markets rise as they
were liberalized. In countries like India sufficient government involvement in
the economy was a hedge against colonial influence and exploitation by free
market countries. Some countries have even been grouped together as new sources
of multinational companies – like BRIC (Brazil, Russia, India, China). Brazil
and India are the two that are more likely to keep free market commitments.
Emerging market countries have been growing their middle classes the most,
increasing demand and continuing fair to robust growth even after the recession.
China’s phenomenal growth is just beginning to slow. China had less exposure to
the recession than other state capitalisms.
Authoritarian governments are more suited to state
capitalism simply because state power and authoritarianism are complementary.
Bremmer goes through state capitalism country by country. Saudi Arabia benefits
from massive revenues, enough to buy the loyalty of its citizens through state
capitalist spending projects. The average person in the other Gulf state
monarchies benefits even more from oil wealth due to smaller populations than
Saudi Arabia. The Saudi’s have been working to diversify away from oil. The
recent downturn in oil prices hurt countries over-reliant on oil, particularly
Venezuela. Oil, petrochemical industry, media, banking, and construction
companies are nationalized in Saudi Arabia. They have eased their protectionism
of late and made some effort at privatization of late.
The United Arab Emirates consists of seven semi-autonomous
emirates, each with a ruling family, with Dubai and Abu Dhabi being the most
powerful. Dubai diversified successfully away from oil long ago and has become
a major international business hub. Abu Dhabi has the most oil wealth. Dubai
has had financial problems since the global recession and has been accused of
over-embracing free markets. Abu Dhabi benefits from sovereign wealth funds.
UAE companies are dominated by companies owned by the seven royal families.
They have free market zones in the country but also practice protectionism and
human rights and censorship issues have been raised.
He goes through Egypt and its history of state involvement.
This is pre-Arab Spring so Mubarek was still around and his son who was his
likely successor was selling off state assets and welcoming foreign investment
in the country. After the global financial crisis they reaffirmed commitment to
free market policies. There are still many state-owned companies.
In Algeria the state has a firm grip on economic policy.
They use Soviet-style five-year plans. They have been proud of their stance
against globalization and predatory foreign investment. They are socialistic
and statist. Algeria has more than a thousand state-owned companies but only
one private sector national champion. Foreign investment in the country is very
small due to excessive state controls.
Ukraine has been struggling away from communism and more
recently from Russian influence. The Orange Revolution in 2005 was followed by
further revolution a few years ago to court more Western influence and shun
excessive Russian influence which has resulted in the conflict there with many
in the Russian-speaking east of the country favoring Russian influence.
Agricultural land is state-owned. There is also considerable corruption as the
country continues to shed its communistic past.
Russia is state capitalist but also has massive corruption,
propaganda, and influence of politicians and key businesspeople. While Putin
has embraced capitalism as the means to help Russia, it is Russian style crony
capitalism. Russia has used its energy leverage considerably to influence other
countries. State-controlled companies like Gazprom (natural gas) and Rosneft
(oil) totally dominate energy. Russia finds it more useful to control powerful
politicians and businesspeople which discourages dissent and pluralism in
politics. While they do allow significant foreign investment in some sectors
they are quite dependent on their oil and gas wealth and thus vulnerable to the
global prices of those commodities. Oligarchs have been essentially forced to
spend money on losing ventures in order to increase employment and stop
layoffs. If they didn’t the state would intervene, sometimes Putin himself.
They have manipulated markets in other “persuasive” ways too. Basically, when
there are problems with maintaining profit at the expense of workers and low
prices the government will step in and order the companies to keep workers and
prices low, giving them money to do so if needed. Thus, Russian-style state
capitalism has been more aggressive. They tried to exhibit strong state control
but also to make it look like that is not the case. President Medvedev,
however, has signaled that strong state-control is a simply a phase in Russian
economics that will eventually fade.
India is not an authoritarian government but a strong
democracy. However, they do exhibit some considerable state capitalist tendencies
and had much state control in their early decades after independence. State
monopolies were broken up and free markets embraced in the early 1990’s. That
continues but there is still some state control. They still have an influential
communist party in their politics. Private companies are now generating
significant wealth in India. State and local-government-owned companies were
responsible for 13% GDP in 2007, down from 17.4% in 1994. Foreign trade only
accounts for 25% of GDP, the lowest of any of the world’s largest economies, so
their embrace of free markets and globalization has room to grow and it is
growing.
In Africa there are some state capitalists but most are
pretty open to foreign investment, especially South Africa. South Africa’s state
policies have been informed by a need to equalize opportunity for
post-apartheid blacks. Nigeria’s policies have sought to maintain a delicate
balance between Muslim majority in the north and Christian majority in the
south. Nigeria is oil-rich and has a state-owned oil company. Corruption and
neglected needs of the poor in the Niger Delta region have hampered the
country.
Elements of state capitalism occur in several countries in
Latin America: Venezuela, Ecuador, Bolivia, and to a lesser extent Argentina.
Market-friendly Mexico has had their highly inefficient state-owned oil company
Pemex privatized recently and is currently welcoming significant foreign
investment in its oil and gas sector, both onshore and offshore. They have been
importing large amounts of natural gas from the U.S. via new pipelines as their
own production drops and their manufacturing economy booms. They have
benefitted from free trade via NAFTA but they also have significant
import/export relationships with other countries and that is being stepped up
in retaliation for Trump’s protectionist policies which seeks to make the
U.S-Mexico relationship more favorable to the U.S.
Brazil is a large emerging market. Foreign trade increased
from 10% to 25% of the economy from 2000 to 2010 and is likely continuing to
grow. Lula de Silva tried to make some reforms increasing state-control in
order to help the poor as in Venezuela and Bolivia but did not do much along
those lines. They still have state-owned oil company Petrobras, some of whose
officials were recently implicated in serious corruption schemes. They have
other state-owned companies but are likely to remain devoted to free markets.
In Southeast Asia there is Indonesia which endured 31 years
of authoritarian rule by Suharto until 1998 with state-owned firms that still
stifle competition by opposing free market reforms. The 1997 Asian financial
crisis reinforced protectionism in Southeast Asia. Free markets have been
embraced by Indonesia since then with some state capitalism retained. Malaysia
has long practiced state capitalism in part to empower ethnic Malays who
compete against wealthy Chinese and Indian minorities. Thus, ethnic identity
politics motivate their state capitalism. Petronas is the national oil &
gas company with total control of hydrocarbons in the country.
In China premier Wen Jiabao gave a statement in a 2008 CNN
interview that Bremmer says amounts to a definition of Chinese state
capitalism: “The complete formulation of our economic policy is to give full
play to the basic role of market forces in allocating resources under the
macroeconomic guidance and regulation of the government.” He also talked about
giving full play in markets to both the ‘invisible hand’ and the ‘visible
hand.’ The Chinese opening to capitalism began with Deng Xiaoping and Zhao
Ziyang. The opening happened deliberately gradual and slow. Of course, state
influence as a guiding principle was always a part of the plan. China joined
the World Trade Organization in 2001. Fear of anarchy (possibly actually
reinforced by Tiananmen Square), he notes, may prevent China from fully
embracing free markets. Of course, their success with them guarantees they
won’t abandon free markets either.
China is focused on providing jobs and supplying oil, gas,
and other commodities. They are busy with both importing and exporting. They
embrace macroeconomic planning and strongly control the banks and have long
been accused of currency manipulation, although the banks are more
market-driven than before after reforms. State-backed companies have bought
into energy and mining ventures across the globe paying high costs and putting
upward pressure on some prices. China was then (2010) supplying 90-95% of rare
earth elements to the market in operations that were environmentally
questionable. They may supply less now as new supplies could weaken their
monopoly. Although foreign investment in China has skyrocketed he suggests
China’s statism could shrink that as state-owned companies become more
efficient and learn to compete better. Cheap Chinese labor has benefited many
multinationals and China needed that investment and the jobs. Certain industries,
however, have been closed to foreign investment. Economic success and growing
middle classes has also stoked Chinese national pride. This makes foreign
investment success less certain. Bush treasury secretary Henry Paulson went to
China to convince them to open up more industries to foreign investment but
then the financial meltdown hit and likely convinced them that their state
influence and protectionism were smart hedges against the volatility of free
markets. They, like many others, blamed the meltdown on failure to properly
regulate. China’s exposure to the free market during the crisis was minimal and
their losses small, with exports facing the biggest loss due to lowered demand
in the U.S., Europe, and Japan. There was some reversal as large state-owned
companies began buying smaller private companies. China became the world’s
largest exporter in 2009. Thus, they will still have to balance the efficiency
and other benefits of free markets with the safety and control of
state-ownership.
China and Russia built up hundreds of billions (or a few
trillion in China’s case) of foreign-exchange reserves and this is economic
power and safety. Bremmer thinks the biggest threat is that Western companies
have become dependent on the Chinese remaining open to free markets and if they
retreat too much those multinationals could lose out. However, that has not
happened in the seven years since this book was published. State capitalism
does distort free markets, he notes. Some stress that free markets thrive on
what’s called “consumer sovereignty,” where producers compete to satisfy
consumers with quality products at the lowest possible cost which benefits
society. When states limit competition, these benefits decrease. Maximizing
shareholder value became the rally cry of public corporations since the 1980’s
when GE CEO Jack Welch began emphasizing it. Of course, problems arose when
companies began over-emphasizing short-term (quarterly) shareholder value over
long-term value and it became more of a game to influence stock prices in the
near-term, often through deception and unnecessary risk-taking. The financial
crisis in the U.S. led to the phrase; “too big to fail,” when a handful of
troubled companies were “bailed out.” However, in state capitalisms such
bailouts are common – in China and Russia for both private and less efficient
state-owned companies. During the financial crisis even Jack Welch reversed his
praise of shareholder value as the sole goal of business.
Authoritarian states have a lot to fear from their own
people so they tend to be strongly protectionist when it comes to trade and
economics. Imposition of quotas and tariffs encourage people to buy domestic
over foreign goods but it also stifles competition, innovation, and tends to
raise prices for goods. He notes that protectionism is a remnant of
mercentalism. He notes that much of the economic growth since 1950 was a direct
result of the easing of protectionism by governments. The WTO, created in 1995,
also worked to limit protectionism and establish trade rules. As of this book
there were 153 WTO member countries that represent about 95% of world trade.
Russia and Algeria are not among them. WTO was designed to aid companies rather
than governments. State capitalist responses to the 2008 financial meltdown
occurred in free market countries all over the world, as temporary prop
measures. State capitalist countries favor protectionism for three reasons: it
is a common recognized policy of sate capitalists, state-owned companies are more
domestically oriented and so do not benefit as much from free market reforms as
do multinational companies, and state capitalist countries are often
authoritarian and so rules favoring free trade are often not in vogue and they
can also practice subtle and secret forms of protectionism. Washington and Wall
Street were largely blamed for the global financial crisis and while it
reinforced the centrality of the U.S. in global business it also showed its
weakness. The slowdown in economic activity in the U.S. affected China since
the U.S. was its best customer and many factories were closed down. China did,
however, rebound quickly back into high growth.
He explores the threats of state capitalism beginning with
the tendency to favor domestic economics at the expense of international
opinion. Here he gives an example of the 2008 military coup in the West African
country of Guinea which involved hundreds of deaths of pro-democracy protestors.
Just a couple weeks later the new government announced a $7 billion deal with a
Chinese mining company. Other risks are involved with the secrecy in which
state-owned companies and sovereign wealth funds operate. The IMF has sought to
make SWFs more transparent. The three biggest pure state capitalist players are
China, Russia, and the Arab monarchies, all countries that have been
adversaries of free market countries in cold wars, oil embargos, and gas supply
manipulations, showing that they can tie their economics to purely political
goals. On the other hand, sovereign wealth funds from Asia and the Middle East
helped with financial market bailouts by investing, although one might conclude
they were bargain hunting by buying low.
Bremmer thinks that state capitalism will eventually fade
away but he is not entirely convinced. Ideologically approaches like communism
have faded and so too might resources nationalism which is partly based on such
ideologies. He calls state capitalism more a set of management techniques than
a coherent political philosophy. As such they are isolated relative to free
market countries and they don’t seamlessly interact in the world economy as
free market countries do – there is mistrust and reluctance to enter into
agreements. The nature of state capitalism is exclusionary, with each country
having their own motives. Even state capitalist countries compete with one
another. While Russia and China have cooperative agreements, they are also
rivals who compete, for instance, for influence in the Central Asian countries
between them. When the Eastern European countries were freed from communism as
Soviet bloc countries there was massive relinquishing of state control.
Relinquishing state control is the main thing that allows countries to become
emerging markets.
“The Great Depression of the 1930’s did not destroy free
market capitalism, even as communist and fascist alternatives captured
imaginations around the world. Free market capitalism defeated fascism, shed
colonialism, and outlasted communism’”
Far and away the private sector is the main driver of
growth, almost the sole driver. Foreign trade and investment also offer the
best means to alleviate poverty around the world. This includes access to free
markets rather than just financial aid which is inadequate in comparison. There
are of course downsides to growth: environmental issues, climate issues, and
resource over-exploitation are some.
He suggests that the recent financial downturn has revived
state capitalism and assured its continued existence in the near-term. Again,
he notes the G7 free market nations is no longer representative of the global
economy but the G20 group which includes several state capitalists probably is.
Free markets function better in open societies which is another reason
authoritarian governments turn to state control. He mentions different models
of free market capitalism:
“The U.S./Anglo-Saxon model grew from mistrust of any system
that gives government too much power. The European social-democratic model
relies more on the state as guardian of the rights of the individual.
Relatively speaking, it favors safeguards for workers over protections for
employers. This can slow growth rates over time, but it provides a wider safety
net when things go wrong.”
State capitalism limits free market systems and they are
growing in terms of influence, particularly China since it has such a huge
population with ever growing production and consumption. Bremmer laments
growing state capitalist influence as it stifles the full flowering potential
of a global free market. For China, state capitalism has become a way to
salvage the remnants of communism by keeping a firm hold on state power while
also participating in the free market. He thinks that over time China will be less
dependent on exporting and diversify their investments away from the dollar.
One problem China faces is creating enough jobs and since free markets mean
faster and more assured growth they are likely to dip into it more as time goes
on. He predicts multinational companies will lose market share (as they have)
in places like China as domestic companies gain it. He favors active promotion
of the virtues of free markets to counter doubts about them enhanced by the
financial crisis. Companies like Exxon-Mobil have essentially sold
technological support in mutually beneficial joint projects. They and others have
become rather indispensable to various national oil companies and that remains
the case in the near-term. He also notes that free-market companies are generally
much more flexible in adapting to fluctuating markets. State capitalisms,
entwined with nationalism, are bounded by the nation’s boundaries while
multinational free market companies that may have branched around the world have
much more flexibility buying and selling in various local markets so they can
better optimize. It has been well-established that “entrepreneurs outperform
political bureaucrats.” While state capitalism can stimulate short-term growth
(which is why free market countries adopted economic stimulus packages after
the financial meltdown) open, free, and fair markets are superior for long-term
growth. He suggests those on the political left who may seem to be pro-state
and con-business relative to those on the right, should point out that the vast
part of the political left also favors free markets. He suggests that a
flourishing private sector is a core American value across the political
spectrum. He also suggests that in most free industrial/developed economies
governments seem to alternate between center-left and center-right (as maybe
they should say some). Europe, although favoring more government interaction
than the U.S., also has strong belief in free markets, despite being depicted
as socialistic by some.
Bremmer recommends keeping foreign trade and investment
robust and holding protectionism at bay. Robust trade and investment will help
the global economy thrive. Of course, no one wants too much foreign investment
and influence in their home country so some deals could be deemed too risky for
political reasons. He also recommends keeping immigration robust, although this
was before mass migration from Syria and other mostly Muslim countries which also
carry the real threat of ISIS-style terrorism. Otherwise, immigration has proved
generally beneficial for both host and donor countries, he suggests. Many
immigrants in the U.S. are Ph.D. scientists and engineers so that is huge plus
to the host country.
China has been accused of currency manipulation to boost its
exports and limit its imports but have pulled back some and in some ways that
has allowed them to invest more in free markets so it’s not all bad news. He
says that the bilateral commercial relationship between China and the U.S. is
the world’s most important. China has apparently cooperated well with WTO rules
and so is coming to be seen as a more reliable economic partner.
Next he mentions Joseph Nye’s concepts of ‘hard power’ and ‘soft
power.’ Hard power refers to “the coercive potential of U.S. military and
economic might.” Soft power refers to the power of American ideas, values, and
culture to “entice and attract.”” Increasing market share and development by
competitor countries erodes the U.S.’s economic hard power so we need to keep
investing in it, he says.
As reflected in the book’s subtitle there is currently
significant competition between free market players and state capitalist
players. The biggest players and the biggest relationship is China and the U.S.
He sees it as a kind of metaphorical Cold War. Observation of reactions to
economic cycles, he suggests, could be key to determining who is “winning” the
cold war.
Great book on economic strategy. I think the title is a bit
misleading since there is no indication at all that the free market will end.
Perhaps a better title would have been – Distortion of the Free Market by State
Capitalist Countries.
No comments:
Post a Comment